EU-Studie empfiehlt Förderung von Freier Software

Liebe Journalisten, das folgende ist ein Thema, was dringend Aufmerksamkeit benötigt. Dabei ist vieles, was man sich vor allem in der Wirtschaftspresse wünschen kann: Innovation, Wirtschaft, Arbeitsplätze, Freiheit, Politik, Europa und vieles mehr.

Die Studie „Economic impact of open source software on innovation and the competitiveness of the Information and Communication Technologies (ICT) sector in the EU“ (PDF / 287 Seiten) wurde federführend von der Uni Masstricht unter der Leitung von Rishab Aiyer Ghosh für die EU-Kommission erstellt. Die Studie betrachtet Freie Software unter Markt-Aspekten im globalen Wettbewerb und formuliert konkrete Handlungsempfehlungen zur Förderung von Freier Software. Dabei handelt es sich vermutlich um die Studie, vor deren Veröffentlichtung die Microsoft-Lobby schon Ende Oktober die EU-Kommission wegen der positiven Ergebnisse für Freie Software gewarnt hat. Das November-Erscheinungsdatum in dem PDF sollte daher nicht verwirren. Veröffentlicht wurde sie erst heute. Ein neuer Vorschlag ist dabei, den wir bisher noch nicht berücksichtigt hatten: Eine Steuerleichterung für die Produktion von Open-Source-Gütern!

Bleibt zu hoffen, dass die Studie auch unser Wirtschaftsministerium erreicht und man sich dort irgendwann wieder mit den Chancen und den richtigen Rahmenbedingungen für Freie Software in Deutschland beschäftigt. Die EU-Ratspräsidentschaft bietet sich dafür an. Auf jeden Fall sehr spannende 287 Seiten.

Hier ist mal eine erste grobe deutsche Übersetzung der konkreten politischen Handlungsempfehlungen:

„Die Verfahrensstrategie befasst sich wesentlich mit der Korrektur gegenwärtiger politischer Linien und Handlungen, welche implizit oder explizit proprietäre Software bevorzugen.

* Die Benachteiligung von FLOSS in Innovation, Forschung und Entwicklung, sowie bei der finanziellen Unterstützung von Forschung und Entwicklung durch die öffentliche Hand, als auch bei der Versorgung der Öffentlichkeit mit Software, welche zurzeit öfters gegen den Wettbewerb gerichtet ist, sollte vermieden werden.

* FLOSS sollte in der vor-wettbewerblichen Forschung und Standardisierung unterstützt werden.

* Die Vermittlung von Fähigkeiten an die Studenten und nicht durch die Vermittlung von speziellen Anwendungen kann Herstellerunabhängigkeit fördern; Studenten können auch Teilnahme an FLOSS-ähnlichen Gemeinschaften befähigt werden.

* FLOSS-Schöpfer sollten eine angemessene steuerliche Behandlung erhalten: die Softwarebeiträge durch FLOSS könnten als wohlfartsartige Spenden behandelt werden. Wo dieses bereits gangbar ist, sollte Aufmerksamkeit unter Firmen, Beteiligten und Verantwortlichen vergrössert werden.

* Die De-packetierung von Hardware und Software kann zu einem wettbewerbsorientierten Markt und einfachen Wegen der Innovation führen, welche durch vertikale Integration nicht gefördert wird. “

Verbesserungen am Besten in den Kommentaren. Wer Zeit und Lust hat, kann auch gleich ganze Abschnitte des Executive-Summery übersetzen. Es dauert vermutlich noch, bis es eine deutsche Version davon gibt und für die Debatte in Deutschland wäre eine Übersetzung hilfreich.

Und hier ist das drei-seitige Executive Summery mit dem „Best of“:

Executive summary: Key findings

The information economy is a large market. Including the provision of infrastructure and services for the creation, exchange and processing of information and communication services as well as the sales of information itself, this market is now in the range of
10% of GDP in most developed countries, and accounts for more than half of their economic growth. Software is one of the key elements driving ICTs’ role in the economy, and the structure, competitiveness, performance of the ICT industry has potential to be strongly affected by Free/Libre/Open Source Software (FLOSS1). Financed by the European Commission’s Directorate General for Enterprise and Industry, a study has been carried out by a team led by UNU-MERIT, the Netherlands, to identify the role of FLOSS in
the economy, its direct impact on the ICT sector, its indirect impact on ICT-related sectors and to recommend policies based on forecasted scenarios.

This three-page executive summary highlights the key findings and recommendations, according to these four categories.

FLOSS role in the economy: market share and geography

• FLOSS applications are first, second or third-rung products in terms of market share in several markets, including web servers, server operating systems, desktop operating systems, web browsers, databases, e-mail and other ICT infrastructure systems. FLOSS market share higher in Europe than in the US for operating systems and PCs, followed by Asia. These market shares have seen considerable growth in the past five years.
• FLOSS market penetration is also high – a large share of private and public organisations report some use of FLOSS in most application domains. In the public sector, Europe has particularly high penetration, perhaps soon to be overtaken by Asia and Latin America. In the private sector, FLOSS adoption is driven by medium- and large-sized firms.
• Almost two-thirds of FLOSS software is still written by individuals; firms contribute about 15% and other institutions another 20%.
• Europe is the leading region in terms of globally collaborating FLOSS software developers, and leads in terms of global project leaders, followed closely by North America (interestingly, more in the East Coast than the West). Asia and Latin America face disadvantages at least partly due to language barriers, but may have an increasing share of developers active in local communities.
• Weighted by regional PC penetration, central Europe and Scandinavia provide disproportionately high numbers of developers; weighted by average income, India is the leading provider of FLOSS developers by far, followed by China.
• While the U.S. has the edge in terms of large FLOSS-related businesses, the greater individual contribution from Europe has led to an increasing number of globally successful European FLOSS small- and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs).

Direct economic impact of FLOSS

• The existing base of quality FLOSS applications with reasonable quality control and distribution would cost firms almost Euro 12 billion to reproduce internally. This code base has been doubling every 18-24 months over the past eight years, and this growth is
projected to continue for several more years.
• This existing base of FLOSS software represents a lower bound of about 131 000 real person-years of effort that has been devoted exclusively by programmers. As this is mostly by individuals not directly paid for development, it represents a significant gap in national accounts of productivity. Annualised and adjusted for growth this represents at least Euro 800 million in voluntary contribution from programmers alone each year, of which nearly half are based in Europe.
• Firms have invested an estimated Euro 1.2 billion in developing FLOSS software that is made freely available. Such firms represent in total at least 565 000 jobs and Euro 263 billion in annual revenue. Contributing firms are from several non-IT (but often ICT intensive) sectors, and tend to have much higher revenues than non-contributing firms.
• Defined broadly, FLOSS-related services could reach a 32% share of all IT services by 2010, and the FLOSS-related share of the economy could reach 4% of European GDP by 2010. FLOSS directly supports the 29% share of software that is developed in-house in the EU (43% in the U.S.), and provides the natural model for software development for the secondary software sector.
• Proprietary packaged software firms account for well below 10% of employment of software developers in the U.S., and “IT user” firms account for over 70% of software developers employed with a similar salary (and thus skill) level. This suggests a relatively
low potential for cannibalisation of proprietary software jobs by FLOSS, and suggests a relatively high potential for software developer jobs to become increasingly FLOSSrelated. FLOSS and proprietary software show a ratio of 30:70 (overlapping) in recent job postings indicating significant demand for FLOSS-related skills.
• By providing a skills development environment valued by employers and retaining a greater share of value addition locally, FLOSS can encourage the creation of SMEs and jobs. Given Europe’s historically lower ability to create new software businesses compared to the US, due to restricted venture capital and risk tolerance, the high share of European FLOSS developers provides a unique opportunity to create new software businesses and reach towards the Lisbon goals of making Europe the most competitive
knowledge economy by 2010.

Indirect economic impact: FLOSS, innovation and growth

• Strong network effects in ICT, the related capitalization for installed dominant players, and some new forms of IPR scope extension risk leading to innovation resources being excessively allocated to defensive innovation. There is a case for a rebalancing of innovation incentives as to create a more equitable environment for innovation that targets publicly available technology for new functionality.
• FLOSS potentially saves industry over 36% in software R&D investment that can result in increased profits or be more usefully spent in further innovation.
• ICT infrastructure has a 10% share of European GDP, providing a basis for a further 2.5% share of GDP in the form of the non-ICT information content industry. However, a large and increasing share of user-generated content is not accounted for and needs to be addressed by policy makers; FLOSS increases the value of the ICT infrastructure, supporting this wider information ecosystem.
• Increased FLOSS use may provide a way for Europe to compensate for a low GDP share of ICT investment relative to the US. A growth and innovation simulation model shows that increasing the FLOSS share of software investment from 20% to 40% would lead to a 0.1% increase in annual EU GDP growth excluding benefits within the ICT industry itself – i.e. over Euro 10 billion annually.

Trends, scenarios and policy strategies

• Equitably valuing the use of FLOSS, the “true” share of software investment rises from 1.7% to 2.3% of GDP in the US by 2010, and from 1% to 1.4% of GDP in Europe. Doubling the rate of FLOSS take-up in Europe would result in a software share of investment at 1.5% of GDP, reducing but not closing this investment gap with the US.
• The notional value of Europe’s investment in FLOSS software today is Euro 22 billion (36 billion in the US) representing 20.5% of total software investment (20% in the US).
• Europe’s strengths regarding FLOSS are its strong community of active developers, small firms and secondary software industry; weaknesses include Europe’s generally low level of ICT investment and low rate of FLOSS adoption by large industry compared to the
• FLOSS provides opportunities in Europe for new businesses, a greater role in the wider information society and a business model that suits European SMEs; FLOSS in Europe threatened by increasing moves in some policy circles to support regulation entrenching
previous business models for creative industries at the cost of allowing for new businesses and new business models.
• Europe faces three scenarios: CLOSED, where existing business models are entrenched through legal and technical regulation, favouring a passive consumer model over new businesses supporting active participation in an information society of “prosumers”;
GENERIC, where current mixed policies lead to a gradual growth of FLOSS while many of the opportunities it presents are missed; VOLUNTARY, where policies and the market develop to recognise and utilise the potential of FLOSS and similar collaborative models
of creativity to harness the full power of active citizens in the information society.

Policy strategies focus mainly on correcting current policies and practices that implicitly or explicitly favour proprietary software:

o Avoid penalising FLOSS in innovation and R&D incentives, public R&D funding and public software procurement that is currently often anti-competitive
o Support FLOSS in pre-competitive research and standardisation
o Avoid lifelong vendor lock-in in educational systems by teaching students skills, not specific applications; encourage participation in FLOSS-like communities
o Encourage partnerships between large firms, SMEs and the FLOSS community
o Provide equitable tax treatment for FLOSS creators: FLOSS software contributions can be treated as charitable donations for tax purposes. Where this is already possible, spread awareness among firms, contributors and authorities.
o Explore how unbundling between hardware and software can lead to a more competitive market and ease forms of innovation that are not favoured by vertical integration.

Update:

Die Heise-Meldung ist relativ langweilig und erkennt meiner Meinung nach nicht die wirklichen Punkte in der Studie: EU-Studie: Open Source zahlt sich aus. Dieses Ergebnis kann man fast aus jeder STudie der letzten Zeit zu Freier Software ziehen.

Golem geht da etwas weiter: EU-Studie sieht Wirtschaftlichkeit von Open Source.

Deine Spende für digitale Freiheitsrechte

Wir berichten über aktuelle netzpolitische Entwicklungen, decken Skandale auf und stoßen Debatten an. Dabei sind wir vollkommen unabhängig. Denn unser Kampf für digitale Freiheitsrechte finanziert sich zu fast 100 Prozent aus den Spenden unserer Leser:innen.

9 Ergänzungen

  1. Die Heise-Meldung ist relativ langweilig und erkennt meiner Meinung nach nicht die wirklichen Punkte in der Studie: EU-Studie: Open Source zahlt sich aus. Dieses Ergebnis kann man fast aus jeder STudie der letzten Zeit zu Freier Software ziehen.

    Na ja, ganz sicher kennt Heise (da sie ja selber damit arbeiten) auch die großen Schwächen von OSS (nur als Beispiel Updates bei Open Office, keine Servicepacks u.ä.) die diese Studie entweder komplett negiert oder aber nur ganz kurz am Rande behandelt.

    Ich vermute, man will sich gerade deshalb in Hannover mal lieber nicht zu weit aus dem Fenster lehnen.

    Sebalin.

Dieser Artikel ist älter als ein Jahr, daher sind die Ergänzungen geschlossen.